This book combines ideas from urban planning and landscape
architecture with ideas from ecology. What is to be gained? A lot of lyrical
passages about the beauty of nature, which grow more and more tiresome the
longer they go on. It's not that the book is without its merits. McHarg's text,
after all, is considered a classic. And when he gets down to practicalities, he
often has intriguing ideas to present. But every other chapter is theory rather
than practicum, and reading this theory fifty years later is like reading a set
of dated truisms amid a collection of late 1960s liberal diatribes.
McHarg especially has it out, it seems, for Christianity,
which he often blames for the environmental ills of the planet. Christianity is
anthropocentric, he denotes, and as such we don't pay attention to the earth's
natural balance. (What, I might ask, would paying attention to the earth's
natural balance entail other than stewardship and a belief in human-centered
superiority? I don't know any cats or dogs or pigs or chickens that worry about
preserving the planet's balance. If they overpopulate or do environmental
damage the earth naturally takes care of it--through evolution, if you will.
The distribution of the animal changes, as does the distribution of the other
animals and plants it affects. So too, one might argue, with humans, if indeed
we are here merely by chance and are merely one other creature among the rest
of the globe's inhabitants. The idea that we need to keep nature balanced, the
way it was supposed to be, is then itself an anthropocentric one, one that
implies that we are somehow above the other creatures on the planet. Anyway,
the constant attacks on Christianity obviously wore thin on me.)
But as I noted, the practicum chapters were of some
interest. An early one discusses the ocean and the beach. Much of this is old
information to me from other reading I've done--how important beach dunes are,
how various attempts to keep beaches in place using groins actually damage
beaches further down, and so on. But it was concrete.
Those sort of points make for interesting studies later in
the book, when McHarg lays out the best ways to, for example, choose where to
lay roads. Too often, he points out, we pay attention chiefly to costs--and by
that, he means, the physical costs, of laying a road. Hence, highways are
placed where there is less development or where development is cheap (i.e.,
poor communitities) and where the land offers the cheapest means to lay the
road (less drilling, etc.). But this often doesn't equate to what the actual
cost is--that is, the actual cost needs to include the culture and social cost.
When we lay down a highway through a community, we're splitting the community
in half and we are likely killing off neighborhoods. And when we lay a road
through pristine forestland that birds use for nesting, we may also be laying
out environmental effects that will in turn affect the social and cultural
ones. His solution? He takes various maps that lay out the different costs
associated with each route for a road. Overlaying this maps allows us to see
which route is likely the most cost effective.
In another practicum chapter, McHarg looks at different
environments that are best for city building, laying out a hierarchy of
preferred land on which to build, in this descending order: flat land, forest,
steep slopes, aquifers, aquifer recharge areas, floodplains, marshes, and
surface water. Knowing these preferences, we should thus really aim not to
build on floodplains and to build on flat land. The only qualifier? Flat land
is also the best land for agriculture, so we have to be attuned to those needs
as well.
In an extended example, McHarg focuses on a plan for the
city of Baltimore and how that city can continue to grow without giving in to
sprawl, selecting the proper places to grow and the proper places to preserve
and what the density in these locations should be.
Next, McHarg turns to a theoretical discussion of how we
would go about creating a proper environment for an astronaut sent to live in
space. He shows how all the various systems are integrated and how difficult it
is to account for everything that nature does naturally. The astronaut easily
can find that he or she has not accounted for some need and throw the system
out of whack. This leads into the chapter on Staten Island, which again is
planned according to different values and needs, using overlaying maps that
give planners the means to know where the best places for conservation are, as
well as the best places for urbanization, both residential and commercial.
In the next theory-heavy section, McHarg approaches a group
of thinkers he calls "Naturalists." Here he lays out the idea that we
need not see evolution, the survival of the fittest, as necessarily negative.
He argues that natural organisms adapt to one another, that the fittest only
surviving is actually a way of advancing nature so that it is more
interdependent. The lion that eats the caribou, for example, is doing the
caribou a favor in terms of keeping its stock lower and also helping it to
evolve to a higher state through only letting the most fit survive. Parasites
depend on hosts, but hosts often adapt to depend also on the parasite. Whole
ecosystems exists because of this interdependence. One of those, arguably, is
our own body, which consists of a host of cells, most of them cells that have
learned to specialize in particular tasks in order to make the body work
together efficiently. The cells are interdependent, supporting a much greater
whole, the way each living thing supports the greater whole of the earth.
Next, McHarg turns to a project on the Potomac River basin.
Much as he has done in earlier chapters, he lays out the various areas as being
most suitable for various resources in order to understand where it would be
best to urbanize and so on. The one intriguing point he makes in this chapter
is that we are too prone to zone things for one use, whereas nature does not
zone: various uses can be gleaned from one area in nature, and we should do the
same in the city. But other than that, the discussion of the Potomac seems like
yet another practicum that repeats information that has gone before. The
techniques to discover what the best places to build are well known by now, and
so the extended examples grow increasingly tiresome.
Potentially, the section on Washington, D.C., could prove
interesting insofar as McHarg attempts to apply his ideas to a city that is
already in existence, rather than to the suburbs of a city that is expanding.
But in the end, I found this section to be disappointing. His main point seems
to be that we need to take into account more than finances when designing
sites. In D.C., it would be important to take into account the
"pallette" of the particular area, make the landscape conform to the
overall tone of the section of the city. Of course, this is easier said than
done, since in the end it is the market that determines how we value space. His
earlier points about taking into account how altering that space affects value
seemed more direct to the point.
The book ends with a chapter on the health of a city, which
is perhaps one of the most interesting and thought provoking. Here, he uses his
mapping system to denote neighborhoods in Philadelphia with various diseases,
mental diseases, and pollution, along with economic troubles, crime, race,
education, unemployment, income, density, and so on. Putting all these together
helps to establish a "healthy" area of the city as being in the north
and west. But why is not as clear. He then goes into studies of population
carried on with rats, showing how density of living has great affects on
health. Though apparently able to have a denser population in their
environment, the rats at some point begin to stop multiplying as fast, and
disease--physical and mental--begins to become more rampant. Those rats that
are dominant don't have the health problems; the rats that are submissive do.
They become loners or sexually deviant or sickly. This, he thinks, is because of
the stressful stimuli that exist in high densities. There seems that there
might be some correlation to human populations as well, as denser areas have
greater amounts of antisocial behavior and sickness. But the ideas, while
intriguing, are not entirely proven or provable. But surely, one wouldn't then
say that humans need to move into suburbs and less dense areas for health
reasons--or would one? Here he briefly looks at how attempts to gentrify
troubled areas with such densities rarely solve the problem. The original
inhabitants are usually pushed out of the area, and what social network they
had to deal with their problems is thus taken apart. I found myself here
wanting to read more about density and its effects.
In the end, then, McHarg notes how we can take into account
various factors of our environment as we build and plan and rework cities. This
is a valid point but one that seemed, in McHarg's reasoning, too bound to its time.
No comments:
Post a Comment